Principles of Taxation
The principles of taxation serve as fundamental guidelines for how governments collect revenue to fund their operations, public services, and social programs. Taxation has evolved over thousands of years, with various forms including income tax, property tax, sales tax, import duties, and specialized taxes for specific programs like Social Security. Income taxes are collected on earnings from multiple sources, while property taxes primarily target real estate and personal property, becoming a significant revenue source for local governments. Sales taxes, levied on consumer purchases, have been a staple for generating revenue at the state level.
In recent years, taxation has increasingly been used as a tool for social policy, influencing behaviors related to health and consumption through targeted taxes on substances like tobacco and alcohol. These taxes aim not only to generate revenue but also to encourage healthier choices among the populace. The rise of e-commerce has introduced new challenges, sparking debates over the taxation of online transactions and necessitating adaptations in tax policy to address these modern economic activities. Overall, the principles of taxation are not just about revenue collection; they encompass complex social considerations that reflect a society's values and priorities.
On this Page
- Overview
- Types of Taxation
- Income Taxes
- Property Taxes
- Consumption (Sales) Taxes
- Fees, Duties & Tariffs
- Specialized Program Taxes
- Tax Collection
- Applications
- Taxes & Social Policy
- Tobacco Taxes for Revenue & Health Reform
- Alcohol Taxes for Revenue & Health Reform
- Issues
- Taxation in the Internet Age
- Conclusion
- Terms & Concepts
- Bibliography
- Suggested Reading
Subject Terms
Principles of Taxation
This article examines the basic principles of taxation and how the current tax structure in the United Sates was first initiated. Five categories of taxes are reviewed including income, property, and sales tax, import tariffs and social program taxes. Tobacco and alcohol taxes are used to illustrate how policy makers attempt to promote social and behavioral changes along with a review of how successful these efforts have been. The evolution of e-commerce and Internet transaction taxes are also examined.
Keywords: Deduction; Earned Income; Exemption; Import Duties; Income Tax; Negative Income Tax; Property Tax; Sales Tax; Social Policy; Social Security System; Tax Administration; Taxing Entity; Tariffs; Tax Policy
Overview
Taxation is a method for governments to raise the funds necessary to pay for operations, capital building projects, and social programs. Some form of tax or another can be traced back to well over 3,000 years ago ("A Short History of Taxation," 2008). Taxes have also been levied to meet increases in demand for revenue and during World War I in the United States, Congress raised taxes to help pay for the cost of the war (Tausig, 1917). The cost for a tax administration system is carried both the governments that levy taxes and by tax payers who must maintain records of taxable activities and file their taxes with the taxing entity ("Tax Policy: Summary," 2005).
Types of Taxation
There are several forms of taxation that fall into five major categories:
- Income taxes
- Property taxes
- Consumption (Sales) taxes
- Fees, duties and tariffs, and
- Specialized taxes
Income Taxes
Taxes on income are levied against individuals and corporations on income they derive from a wide variety of sources. Income taxes have been used by governments to generate revenue to pay for government operations. In the United States the income tax was first used to help pay for the cost of the Civil War ("Story of the Income Tax," 1944). During the 1800s several state and local governments also started taxing income in a variety of manners (Kinsman, 1909). Income is earned from a numerous sources including sale of goods or services, interest on bank accounts or bonds, sale of assets, and sale of stocks to name just a few. These sources of income can be taxed at different rates depending on the policies of the taxing entity.
Property Taxes
Taxes on property are charged by governments on real estate holdings, business assets and equipment, and personal property owned by private citizens. Property taxes are levied by state and local governments on real estate holdings, business assets and equipment, and personal property owned by private citizens (Hale, 1985). Property tax has become the primary source of revenue for most local governments and provides more revenue than income taxes or sales taxes. In most states property taxes are collected on all property with the exception of that owned by religious and charitable organizations or on property owned by government entities. If property taxes are not paid by the owners the taxing government places a lien on the property. The past due property taxes must be paid before title of the property can be transferred and in cases where large sums of overdue taxes are owed, the government can seize the property and sell it to raise the owed taxes (Fisher, 1997).
Consumption (Sales) Taxes
Taxes on economic activities are often referred to as consumption taxes which are levied on the purchase of goods and services. Consumption taxes, which are levied on the purchase of goods and services, have been used by governments for centuries ("A Short History of Taxation," 2008). In the United States the first consumption tax was levied in 1791 on distilled spirits ("The Story of Federal Taxation," 1936). Since then most states have instituted some form of sales taxes when property, goods, or services are purveyed or transferred (Watts, 1938). The general sales tax became popular at the state level in the 1930s and in most transactions sales tax is collected by businesses and then submitted to the state departments of revenue on a periodic basis (Cornia, et al., 2000). Currently there are more than 7,000 government entities in the United States that levy some type of sales tax (Haas, 2004).
Fees, Duties & Tariffs
Taxes on the international movement of many products are often referred to as customs fees, duty, or tariffs ("A Short History of Taxation," 2008). The United States first started collecting duty on imported goods in 1789 when the Customs service was established. The country then needed money to pay for the formation of the new government ("A Continuing Tradition..," 2009). Prior to the implementation and maturation of the income tax programs in the United States import duties accounted for one of the largest sources of income for the government. More than $25 billion per year was collected on imported items in the early 21st century ("International Trade," 2006).
Specialized Program Taxes
Finally, there are specialized taxes that have been instituted to pay for government programs. The social security system in the United States is one of the largest programs for which a specific tax is levied. It was started as a result of the great depression of the 1920s and 1930s by President Franklin D. Roosevelt (Martin & Weaver, 2005). The program provides retirement benefits for the elderly and a wide variety of benefits for people that are disabled ("Social Security Act of 1935," 2009). The Social Security Act also established Medicare, which is the largest health insurance program in the United States ("Medicare," 2008). Although popular among benefit recipients, it has long been known that Social Security systems in several countries will face fiscal strains in the future as the number of workers paying in their social security taxes declines compared to the number of people receiving benefits (Börsch-Supan, 1991).
Tax Collection
At the national level in the United States, the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) is responsible for collecting taxes based on income. The IRS was established under President Lincoln in 1862 to collect taxes to help pay for the Civil War. Ratified in 1913, the 16th Amendment to the Constitution gave Congress the authority to pass laws which permanently created the Federal income tax ("Brief History of IRS," 2009). The IRS is currently organized into several major divisions that focus on tax administration activities ("At-a-Glance," 2009).
In 2008, the IRS processed over 230 million tax returns ("Tax Stats," 2008) and in 2005 American tax payers paid over $2 trillion per year in Federal taxes ("Summary of Estimates," 2005). In addition, there are over $300 billion in taxes that are due to the Federal government every year that are not paid. This unpaid amount is often referred to as the tax gap ('Reducing the Tax Gap," 2005).
The collection of state taxes is most often managed by the State Departments of Revenue. A similar structure is also found in counties across the United States. The organization of state and local revenue collection functions depends on the types of taxes that are being collected. As with the federal government, tax monies collected by the tax administration agency are turned over to the treasury department or a function of thaat government entity.
Applications
Taxes & Social Policy
Taxation is not just a means of raising money to pay for wars or government operations. Taxation has evolved into a method of implementing social policy and has been used to influence business practices as well as individual behavior (Berliant & Rothstein, 2003).
Several tax laws in the United States are designed to either provide rewards or penalties for the way corporations or individuals behave. One such tax policy is known as the negative income tax, which simultaneously helps to support poor families while providing an incentive for heads of households to work in paying jobs (Moffitt, 2003). In both of these cases, tax policy is addressing the disparate distribution of wealth and resources in modern societies (Steinmo, 2003).
The social and political debate about the design of the tax system and the purpose and effectiveness of various taxes is endless. The principles behind tax policies can be very complex as well as riddled with bias ("Understanding the Tax Reform Debate," 2005). In the United States there are opposing forces that attempt to influence tax policy for their advantage or in line with philosophical or political points of view. Corporations of course attempt to influence policy makers that they should not pay high taxes or they work to pressure local governments to reduce corporate property taxes. Republicans and Democrats are often opposed in their views on tax policy, as are religious conservatives and social liberals (Peele, 2005). There are also various non-economic social factors that influence tax payers' viewpoints about the fairness of tax laws (Ackert, Martinez-Vasquez & Rider, 2004).
Several theories have been put forth as to how and why humans consume addictive substances. Likewise, there are conflicting theories about the relationship between the cost of consuming addictive substances and patterns of consumption. Some of these theories have been adopted by individuals, social agencies, and government policy makers in efforts to use economics as a deterrent to the consumption of addictive substances. They believe that if taxes are increased on legalized addictive substances, more people will consume fewer of these substances. As a result, numerous tax laws have been passed to heavily tax tobacco and alcohol (Andersson, Bask, & Melkersson, 2006).
Tobacco Taxes for Revenue & Health Reform
Tobacco taxes have historically been a very good source of revenue for local, state, and federal governments. However, since the United States Surgeon General's report on the harmful health effects of tobacco use was released in 1964, governments have been steadily increasing tobacco taxes to reduce smoking and to offset the negative impact of tobacco-related illness on healthcare costs (Meier & Licari, 1997). The public sentiment towards tobacco has shifted since the 1964 Surgeon General's report, but not without considerable debate and lobbying efforts by those supporting tobacco and those opposing tobacco (Givel, 2006).
The goal of the World Health Organization (WHO) has been to get countries around the world to address tobacco usage and the health problems that result. The WHO supported the Framework Convention on Tobacco Control (FCTC), an agreement among the 192 member countries of the WHO designed to decrease tobacco use. The WHO has presented evidence that in countries that have increased the tobacco tax, support public awareness programs on the hazards of smoking, and place restrictions on where people can smoke have succeeded in reducing tobacco use (Chaloupka, Jha, et al, 2003).
Although taxes on cigarettes vary from country to country, they generally comprise thirty to fifty percent of the cost of cigarettes. Policy makers have hoped that higher taxes on cigarettes would deter people from smoking by increasing their personal smoking costs (Hoang Van, et al, 2006). There is however, debate as to the long-term effectiveness of higher taxes to reduce tobacco consumption. Since these efforts have been in place for less than two decades it may be difficult to determine if higher tobacco taxes will actually reduce consumption (Sugarman, 2003).
Alcohol Taxes for Revenue & Health Reform
Over the last several decades many health officials and law enforcement agencies have taken the position that alcohol causes considerable health and social problems. Like higher tobacco taxes, the effectiveness of higher alcohol taxes for the purpose of decreasing consumption is heavily debated ("Alcohol Tax," 1987). In fact, distilled spirits were among the first items to have a consumption tax in the United States ("The Story of Federal Taxation," 1936). When the impact of the rise and fall of alcohol prices on consumption have been studied no clear relationships between price and consumption could be found. It also seems that national cultures impact the consumption patterns more than price (Mäkel, Bloomfield, et al., 2008).
Even though the debate over whether or not higher alcohol taxes and thus high alcohol prices will deter consumption seems to be unsettled, there is still the debate about the economic impact of higher alcohol taxes. Producers of alcoholic beverages as well as purveyors of alcoholic beverages such as liquor stores, bars, and restaurants of course want to protect their economic interest. They do not want consumption to decrease because it will negatively impact their sales and their profits (Cook, 1982; Giesbrecht, Greenfield, et al., 2004).
Alcohol taxes have also been turned into a competitive tool for adjoining jurisdictions at the state, county, and local level. The government entities that restrict alcohol consumption or heavily tax alcohol consumption are frequently bordered or are in close vicinity to other communities or states that use liberalized consumption laws and lower taxes to attract consumers (Rinaldi, 2007). In this situation tax policy is being used to influence consumptive behavior from two different directions. One side wants to reduce consumption while the other side wants to increase consumption and thus gain tax revenues from the direct sales of alcohol as well as other products or services that may be consumed along with alcohol.
Issues
Taxation in the Internet Age
The Internet has created a tax debate at the local, state, national, and international levels. The primary issue is the collection of sales tax on e-commerce transactions that occur across international borders and state lines. There are also debates about charging taxes for Internet access services as well as web-based services provided by a variety of pay-per-use web sites (Haas, 2004; Stanton, 2007). In an effort to promote e-commerce and the growth of the Internet the United States Congress passed the Internet Tax Freedom Act (ITFA) which expired in 2003, theoretically leaving states and other jurisdictions free to pursue their own sales tax issues (Haas, 2004). However, the taxation of Internet access services met with intense opposition was again delayed by congressional action (Schroeder, 2007).
At the heart of the debate over Internet taxes is the taxation of sales across state lines in the United States. In 1992 the United States Supreme Court decided in the Quill Corporation versus North Dakota case that sellers could not be required to collect sales or use taxes for transactions unless they had physical sales locations within that state. Government entities that collect sales taxes have been opposed to this proposition even though buyers are often legally required to voluntarily submit the sales tax that is due to the state (Vadum, 2000).
As the amount of such uncollected sales tax grew into the billions of dollars, various government associations started to aggressively lobby to gain access to those tax dollars ("Alliance," 1999). Although it has been difficult to estimate lost tax dollars because of Internet sales, local governments remained steadfast in their desire and their efforts to tax Internet transactions (Meisler, 1998; Miller, 2004). Meanwhile, free market advocates remained active in their efforts to block governments from collecting taxes on Internet transactions as well as assure that taxing entities did not attempt to charge higher tax rates for Internet transactions (Ponnuru, 2000).
Another challenge that taxing entities face is how to actually collect taxes from Internet sales in a manner that is cost effective. Whatever the processes a taxing entity uses to administer its tax system the administrative costs should not exceed the amount of taxes that are collected (Goolsbee & Zittrain, 1999). The burden on the taxpayer also needs to be considered and requiring Internet sellers to send numerous checks and sales records to different taxing entities could become rather burdensome for them as well (Lukas, 2001).
In order to simplify the process of collecting taxes on Internet sales government entities banded together on the Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Agreement (SSUTA). The agreement is designed to establish a uniform process that would ease the collection of taxes by government entities and hopefully provide greater ease for sellers in paying the taxes that are due (De Rugy, 2002; Feinschreiber & Kent, 2003). The SSUTA went into effect in 2005 ("Streamlined," 2005) and within three years, one thousand sellers were voluntarily collecting sales tax on remote sales (Blackston, 2008).
In 2008 the SSUTA continued the debate on how to tax digital products and determined that digital products should not be taxed as tangible personal property, though member states were left free to tax digital products in other manners (Harris & Kulwicki, 2008).
As state budgets shrivelled during the 2008-2009 recession and lingering financial downturn, the issue was revisited by Congress, and the Marketplace Fairness Act was passed in 2013. The act at last provided a framework for state taxation of Internet commerce by allowing states to require Internet sellers doing annual business of more than $1 million to collect and remit sales taxes to the states in which sales originate, thus overriding the standing legal objection that the seller must also have a presence in the state in with the sale originates. Internet retailers had objected that the logistics of sorting out remittances to the states, which vary widely in their sales tax laws, was too onerous. The act dealt with this objection by restricting the requirement to states that abide by the Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Agreement (SSUTA) (Yang, 2013). Brick and mortar retailers applauded the act for levelling the playing field, at least somewhat (Adams, 2013).
Conclusion
Taxation is virtually universal among all countries, states, and local governments. The five major types of taxes are also used to some extent in industrialized countries around the world. In terms of revenue for government operations, income taxes and property taxes yield the largest amounts of revenue. In addition, specialized taxes, such as those that support the social security system in the United States, are designed to make such programs self-sufficient.
Although taxation is commonly accepted, policies on what to tax and how much to tax are always being debated. When social policy is executed through the taxation process the debate about taxes can be even more heated. In the case of tobacco and alcohol taxes policy makers and anti-tobacco and anti-alcohol advocates are now in agreement that these items should be taxed heavily. The impact of higher taxes on the consumption of addictive substances has yet to be proven. That is with the exception that higher taxes can yield more revenue for taxing entities. The desired shifts in social behavior, on the other hand may be temporarily effective but it is too soon to tell if they will have the desired impact in the long term.
The Internet has created new debates about taxes and has presented policy makers and taxing entities with new challenges. At the Federal level government policy has been favoring the economic growth that has resulted from e-commerce and other digital services and products. At the local and state level the perception has been that those taxing entities were losing out on revenue, The battle over Internet taxes and digital property taxes is far from over and it will likely be many years before taxation practices can actually catch up to the new digital age.
Terms & Concepts
Negative Income Tax: A tax systems designed to incent lower income people to work by providing tax rebates for earned income and that structures tax credits in a manner that supports the continued economic productivity of the individual.
Social Policy: Laws, regulations, and methods by which a government attempts to reengineer society and control or change the behavior of individuals or corporations.
Social Security: A government program that provides benefits to selected classes of recipients based on government policy, required participation or the individual, and eligibility under program regulations.
Tax Administration: The organization, personnel, facilities, and technology that a government entity needs to collect taxes and tax payers need to maintain records, analyze income, and submit tax payments.
Taxing Entity: The national, state, county, or local government entity that has the authority to levy a tax.
The Great Depression: The global economic collapse that started after World War I and was accelerated by the stock market crashes of the late 1920s. Government intervention was required for economic recovery and numerous social programs and government policies designed to stabilize the economy were enacted.
Bibliography
A continuing tradition of 220 years of service to the nation. (2009). Retrieved October 5, 2009 from U.S. Customs and Border Protection. http://www.cbp.gov/xp/cgov/about/history/220%5fcustoms.xml
A short history of taxation. (2008, October). New Internationalist, , 16-17. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=35580735&site=ehost-live
Ackert, L., Martinez-Vasquez, J., & Rider, M. (2004). Tax policy design in the presence of social preferences: Some experimental evidence. Working Paper Series (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta), 2004, 1-33. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=15389294&site=ehost-live
Adams, M. (2013). Online sales tax could pump up retail values. Real Estate Finance & Investment, 23. Retrieved November 15, 2013, from EBSCO Online Database Business Source Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=bth&AN=87804756&site=ehost-live
Alcohol tax policy reform. (1987). American Journal of Public Health, 77, 106-111. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=21090912&site=ehost-live
Alliance of counties calls for net taxes. (1999). Journal of Internet Law, 3, 26. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=7023898&site=ehost-live
Andersson, L., Bask, M., & Melkersson, M. (2006). Economic man and the consumption of addictive goods: The case of two goods. Substance Use & Misuse, 41, 453-466. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=19978321&site=ehost-live
At-a-glance: IRS divisions and principal offices. (2009). Retrieved October 5, 2009 from The United States Internal Revenue Service. http://www.irs.gov/irs/article/0,,id=149199,00.html
Berliant, M., & Rothstein, P. (2003). Possibility, impossibility, and history in the origins of the marriage tax. National Tax Journal, 56, 303-317. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Business Source Premier. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=10598488&site=ehost-live
Blackston, M. (2008). Closing the online tax loophole. State Legislatures, 34, 24-25. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Business Source Premier. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=31717970&site=ehost-live
Börsch-Supan, A. (1991). Aging population: Problems and policy options in the US and Germany. Economic Policy, 6, 103-139. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=15158031&site=ehost-live
Brief history of IRS. (2009). Retrieved October 5, 2009 from The United States Internal Revenue Service. http://www.irs.gov/irs/article/0,,id=149200,00.html
Chaloupka, F., Jha, P., Corrao, M., Silva, V., Ross, H., Ciecierski, C., et al. (2003). Global efforts for reducing the burden of smoking. Disease Management & Health Outcomes, 11, 647-661. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=11084828&site=ehost-live
Cook, P. (1982). Alcohol taxes as a public health measure. British Journal of Addiction, 77, 245-250. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=6273185&site=ehost-live
Cornia, G., Edmiston, K., Sheffrin, S., Sexton, T., Sjoquist, D., & Zorn, C. (2000). An analysis of the feasibility of implementing a single rate sales tax. National Tax Journal, 53, 1327-1350. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=3973760&site=ehost-live
De Rugy, V. (2002). State bureaucrats plot higher Internet taxes. Human Events, 58, 10. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=8683566&site=ehost-live
Feinschreiber, R., & Kent, M. (2003). Understanding the streamlined sales and use tax agreement. Corporate Business Taxation Monthly, 4, 21. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=9294639&site=ehost-live
Fisher, G. (1997). Some lessons from the history of the property tax. (Cover story). Assessment Journal, 4, 40. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=9709036182&site=ehost-live
Giesbrecht, N., Greenfield, T., Anglin, L., & Johnson, S. (2004). Changing the price of alcohol in the United States: Perspectives from the alcohol industry, public health, and research. Contemporary Drug Problems, 31, 711-736. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=16724413&site=ehost-live
Givel, M. (2006). Punctuated equilibrium in limbo: The tobacco lobby and U.S. state policymaking from 1990 to 2003. Policy Studies Journal, 34, 405-418. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=21808966&site=ehost-live
Goolsbee, A., & Zittrain, J. (1999). Evaluating the costs and benefits of taxing Internet commerce. National Tax Journal, 52, 413-428. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=2387452&site=ehost-live
Hale, D. (1985). The evolution of the property tax: A study of the relation between public finance and political theory. Journal of Politics, 47, 382. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=4814056&site=ehost-live
Haas, A. (2004). Internet taxation: The battle begins! Journal of State Taxation, 23, 43-50. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=14901308&site=ehost-live
Harris, S., & Kulwicki, L. (2008). Update on streamlined sales and use tax agreement: Taxation of digital products. Corporate Business Taxation Monthly, 9, 13-38. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=29728692&site=ehost-live
Hoang Van, K., Ross, H., Levy, D., Nguyen Thac, M., & Vu Thi Bich, N. (2006). The effect of imposing a higher, uniform tobacco tax in Vietnam. Health Research Policy & Systems, 4, 6-16. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=28747881&site=ehost-live
International trade: Customs' revised bonding policy reduces risk of uncollected duties, but concerns about uneven implementation and effects remain. (2006). Report to the Chairman, Committee on Ways and Means, House of Representatives. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from The United States Government Accountability Office. http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d0750.pdf
Kinsman, D. (1909). The present period of income tax activity in the American states. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 23, 296-306. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=9386209&site=ehost-live
Lewit, E. (1989). U.S. tobacco taxes: Behavioral effects and policy implications. British Journal of Addiction, 84, 1217-1134 Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=6609073&site=ehost-live
Lukas, A. (2001). Should Internet sales be taxed? USA Today Magazine, 129(2668), 14. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=3933728&site=ehost-live
Mäkel, P., Bloomfield, K., Gustafsson, N., Huhtanen, P., & Room, R. (2008). Changes in volume of drinking after changes in alcohol taxes and travellers' allowances: Results from a panel study. Addiction, 103, 181-191. 1134 Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=28352108&site=ehost-live
Martin, P., & Weaver, D. (2005). Social Security: A program and policy history. Social Security Bulletin, 66, 1-15. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=19262092&site=ehost-live
Medicare: Thousands of Medicare Part B providers abuse the federal tax system. (2008). Testimony Before the Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations, Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs, U.S. Senate. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from The United States Government Accountability Office. http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d07587t.pdf
Meier, K., & Licari, M. (1997). The effect of cigarette taxes on cigarette consumption, 1955 through 1994. American Journal of Public Health, 87, 1126-1130. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=9708130605&site=ehost-live
Meisler, D. (1998). Let taxes trail sales from stores to Web, groups urge. Bond Buyer, 325(30471), 1. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=1038805&site=ehost-live
Miller, M. (2004). Technology and politics: The choices For 2004. PC Magazine, 23, 7-8. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=11921210&site=ehost-live
Moffitt, R. (2003). The negative income tax and the evolution of U.S. welfare policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 119-140. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=10879934&site=ehost-live
Peele, G. (2005). Electoral politics, ideology and American social policy. Social Policy & Administration, 39, 150-165. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=16341928&site=ehost-live
Ponnuru, R. (2000). The tax man cometh. National Review, 52, 44-46. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=3184849&site=ehost-live
Rinaldi, G. (2007). The use of economic tools to develop a consensus on alcohol policies within and between jurisdictions. Contemporary Drug Problems, 34, 729-751. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=34697019&site=ehost-live
Schroeder, P. (2007). Bush signs into law seven-year extension of ban on Internet taxes. Bond Buyer, 362(32746), 6. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=27392306&site=ehost-live
Stanton, L. (2007). Despite progress in state-industry talks, issues remain in Internet tax debate. Telecommunications Reports, 73, 8-9. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=26225307&site=ehost-live
Steinmo, S. (2003). The evolution of policy ideas: Tax policy in the 20th century. British Journal of Politics & International Relations, 5, 206-236. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=9724170&site=ehost-live
Story of the income tax. (1944). Congressional Digest, 23, 260-262. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=12060455&site=ehost-live
Streamlined sales tax agreement goes into effect. (2005). State Legislatures, 31, 5. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=19054550&site=ehost-live
Sugarman, S. (2003). A balanced tobacco control policy. American Journal of Public Health, 93, 416-418. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=9248239&site=ehost-live
Table 2: Numbers of Returns Filed by Type of Return Fiscal Years 2007 and 2008. (2008). Retrieved October 5, 2009 from The United States Internal Revenue Service. http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/08db02nr.xls
Tausig, F. (1917). The War Tax Act of 1917. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 32, 1-37. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=9200732&site=ehost-live
Tax policy: Summary of estimates of the costs of the federal tax system. (2005, August). Report to Congressional Requesters. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from The United States Government Accountability Office. http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d05878.pdf
The story of federal taxation in american history. (1936). Congressional Digest, 15, 135-137. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=11904482&site=ehost-live
Understanding the tax reform debate: Background, criteria, and questions: GAO-05-1009S. (2005). GAO Reports, 1. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=18215071&site=ehost-live
United States Congress. (1935). Social Security Act of 1935. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=21212308&site=ehost-live
Vadum, M. (2000). Cox: Congress won't expand state sales tax powers for Internet. Bond Buyer, 331(30816), 5. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=2762056&site=ehost-live
Walker, D. (2005, April 14). Reducing the tax gap can contribute to fiscal sustainability but will require a variety of strategies. Testimony Before the Committee on Finance, U. S. Senate. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from The United States Government Accountability Office. http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d05527t.pdf
Watts, D. (1938). History and development of the sales tax. Congressional Digest, 17, 265-267. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=11954993&site=ehost-live
Yang, J.S. (2013). The impact of the Marketplace Fairness Act of 2013 on internet commerce taxation. Journal of State Taxation, 32, 13-45. Retrieved November 15, 2013, from EBSCO Online Database Business Source Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=bth&AN=91821940&site=ehost-live
Suggested Reading
A statement of tax concepts to be used as a basis for teaching income taxation. (1969). Accounting Review, 44, 1-18. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=4481881&site=ehost-live
Alexander, A. (2000). The tax policy regime in American politics, 1941-1951. Congress & the Presidency, 27, 59. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=3307809&site=ehost-live
Banthin, C. (2004). Cheap smokes: State and federal responses to tobacco tax evasion over the Internet. Health Matrix: Journal of Law Medicine, 14, 325-356. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=14497482&site=ehost-live
Boyd, R., & Seldon, B. (1991). Revenue and land-use effects of proposed changes in sin taxes: A general equilibrium perspective. Land Economics, 67, 365. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=5362986&site=ehost-live
Buehler, A. (1931). The general sales tax in the fiscal system. Harvard Business Review, 9, 348-359. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=6765771&site=ehost-live
Cahoon, C., & Brown, W. (1973). The interstate tax dilemma — a proposed solution. National Tax Journal, 26, 187-197. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=4583314&site=ehost-live
Conway, K. (1997). Labor supply, taxes, and government spending: A microeconometric analysis. Review of Economics & Statistics, 79, 50-67. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=9709284185&site=ehost-live
Cornick, P. (1959). The property tax and housing. American Journal of Economics & Sociology, 19, 17-25. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=15361940&site=ehost-live
Elliott, G. (2005). Imported works of art face higher taxes. Accountancy, 135(1340), 112. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=16806666&site=ehost-live
Fortune, J. (1972). Excise taxes, tariffs and imports. Applied Economics, 4, 197. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=4619575&site=ehost-live
Furman, J. (2008). Health reform through tax reform: A primer. Health Affairs, 27, 622-632. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=31967816&site=ehost-live
Garner, C. (2005). Consumption taxes: Macroeconomic effects and policy issues. Economic Review (01612387), 90, 5-29. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=17386035&site=ehost-live
Gemmell, N., & Morrissey, O. (2005). Distribution and poverty impacts of tax structure reform in developing countries: How little we know. Development Policy Review, 23, 131-144. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=16146127&site=ehost-live
Greenhut, M., & Norman, G. (1986). Spatial pricing with a general cost function: The effects of taxes on imports. International Economic Review, 27, 761. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from Academic Search Complete database. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=5695060&site=ehost-live
Irwin, D. (1998). Changes in U.S. tariffs: The role of import prices and commercial policies. American Economic Review, 88, 1015. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=1179488&site=ehost-live
Jeske, K., & Kitao, S. (2005). Health insurance and tax policy. Working Paper Series (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta), 2005, 1-27. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=18391485&site=ehost-live
Koski, A., Sirén, R., Vuori, E., & Poikolainen, K. (2007). Alcohol tax cuts and increase in alcohol-positive sudden deaths — a time-series intervention analysis. Addiction, 102, 362-368. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=23938170&site=ehost-live
Maroney, J., Rupert, T., & Wartick, M. (2002). The perceived fairness of taxing social security benefits: The effect of explanations based on different dimensions of tax equity. Journal of the American Taxation Association, 24, 79-92. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=8885558&site=ehost-live
Martinez, M. (1997). Don't tax you, don't tax me, tax the fella behind the tree: Partisan and turnout effects on tax policy. Social Science Quarterly (University of Texas Press), 78, 895-906. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=127249&site=ehost-live
McNulty, J. (2000). Flat tax, consumption tax, consumption-type income tax proposals in the United States: A tax policy discussion of fundamental tax reform. California Law Review, 88, 2095. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=4061485&site=ehost-live
Mieszkowski, P. (1966). The comparative efficiency of tariffs and other tax-subsidy schemes as a means of obtaining revenue or protecting domestic production. Journal of Political Economy, 74, 587. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=5055907&site=ehost-live
Moore, M. (1996). Death and tobacco taxes. RAND Journal of Economics, 27, 415-428. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=9606192139&site=ehost-live
Rivlin, A. (1989). The continuing search for a popular tax. American Economic Review, 79, 113. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=4507385&site=ehost-live
Rolph, E. (1950). Equity versus efficiency in federal tax policy. American Economic Review, 40, 391. Retrieved October 5, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=8750864&site=ehost-live
Snavely, K. (1988). Innovations in state tax administration. Public Administration Review, 48, 903-910. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=4593744&site=ehost-live
Stone, E. (2005). Adhering to the old line: Uncovering the history and political function of the unrelated business income tax. Emory Law Journal, 54, 1475-1556. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=20194236&site=ehost-live
Thorson, D. (1965). An analysis of the sources of continued controversy over the tax treatment of family income. National Tax Journal, 18, 113-132. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=4584730&site=ehost-live
Tin-Chun, L. (2006). The impact of corporation income tax policy on investment expenditures: A United States survey. International Journal of Management, 23, 412-418. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=22433907&site=ehost-live
Weinrobe, M. (1971). Corporate taxes and the United States balance of trade. National Tax Journal, 24, 79-86. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=4585589&site=ehost-live
Yeates, N. (2005). The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS): What's in it for Social Security? International Social Security Review, 58, 3-22. Retrieved September 30, 2009, from EBSCO online database, Academic Search Complete. http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=15876550&site=ehost-live