West Germany Bans Immigration of Workers from Outside the EEC
On November 23, 1973, the West German government announced a significant policy shift by banning the immigration of foreign workers from outside the European Economic Community (EEC). This decision ended a longstanding practice that had facilitated the influx of millions of laborers from various nations to meet the demands of a recovering German economy post-World War II. For over a decade, West Germany had welcomed workers from countries like Italy, Greece, Turkey, and Yugoslavia, driven by population pressures and economic opportunities in their home regions.
The ban coincided with broader economic challenges, including rising unemployment in West Germany and other EEC nations, influenced by the oil shocks of the 1970s. By this time, foreign workers represented about 10% of the workforce, filling roles often deemed unattractive to local inhabitants. The cessation of recruitment marked a pivotal moment in European labor dynamics, leading to increased xenophobia and tensions as native unemployment rates began to rise.
As the EEC had promoted the free movement of labor among its members, West Germany's restriction reflected a growing sentiment among many European nations against further immigration, driven by concerns over population density and resource allocation. Countries like the Netherlands soon followed suit with similar restrictions. This policy shift had profound implications for the labor-exporting nations, particularly Turkey and Yugoslavia, exacerbating urbanization issues and contributing to significant socio-economic challenges in those regions.
West Germany Bans Immigration of Workers from Outside the EEC
Date November 23, 1973
The Federal Republic of Germany announced that it would cease all recruiting of workers from countries outside the Common Market, thus reversing a policy in place for more than a decade.
Locale West Germany
Key Figures
Walter Arendt (1925-2005), West German minister of labor and social welfare, 1969-1976Willy Brandt (Herbert Ernst Karl Frahm;1913-1992), chancellor of West Germany, 1969-1974Josef Stingl (1919-2004), director of the German Labor Exchange, 1968-1984
Summary of Event
On November 23, 1973, the West German government announced that it would no longer admit foreigners seeking work in Germany who came from countries outside the European Common Market. It thus brought to an end a policy that had characterized the German employment scene for more than a decade.
In the early years following World War II, the inhabitants of the western occupation zones, which were later to become the Federal Republic of Germany, were flooded with people from elsewhere. Some twelve million Germans, formerly residents of territories claimed by the victorious Allies, poured into the three western occupation zones from the Baltic States, East Prussia, Danzig, Silesia, the Sudetenland, Poland, Hungary, Romania, and Yugoslavia. There were at least 100,000 refugees from the Soviet forces who could not be repatriated. Thus, in the first years after the end of World War II, Germany had no lack of individuals willing to work, facing instead a lack of jobs.
As the West German economy began to recover under the stimulus provided by the Marshall Plan, industry required more workers. At the same time, as the economy in the Soviet zone faltered under the heavy load of reparations, many Germans who had lived for years in that part of Germany fled to the west. Before erection of the Berlin Wall in 1961, three million East Germans managed to make it across the zonal border and added to the numbers already living in western Germany. West Germany also offered a sanctuary to some 800,000 people of German extraction who had settled in Poland and the Soviet Union years earlier. Together, the native inhabitants of West Germany and all these new immigrants added up to 62 million people. The population was one of the densest in Europe, with 250 people per square kilometer.
Thanks to currency reform, Marshall Plan aid, and a strong work ethic, German industry created jobs for all the West German inhabitants able and willing to work. From the early 1950’s to the late 1960’s, West Germany enjoyed full employment. In the late 1950’s and throughout most of the 1960’s, there were more jobs than could be filled from the native population. These unfilled jobs provided a magnet for people from other parts of Europe, where job opportunities were less plentiful.
The first to take advantage of the many job opportunities were Italians, especially Italians from central and southern Italy. Italians poured north of the Alps, principally to Germany but also to France, Belgium, the Netherlands, and even tiny Luxembourg. By the mid-1960’s, however, the pent-up pressure from underdeveloped southern Italy had been relieved. Thereafter, as the need for labor continued in Germany, it had to be met from elsewhere. Workers came from Spain, Portugal, Greece, Turkey, and Yugoslavia. By 1974, 2.2 million foreign workers held jobs in West Germany; they amounted to about 10 percent of the workforce.
The root cause of this large migration was population pressure in the underdeveloped parts of Europe and the Mediterranean basin. Both Greece and Turkey, for example, had population growth rates that vastly exceeded the number of jobs being created in their underdeveloped economies. One expert estimated in the late 1960’s that ifcurrent trends continued, by 1980 Greece would have between 270,000 and 670,000 excess workers and Turkey would have between 4.3 and 5.4 million. These pressures propelled large numbers of Greeks and Turks, and later Yugoslavs, northward and westward into Germany, where many took jobs that German workers scorned, including unskilled or semiskilled work in factories and “dirty” service-sector jobs such as garbage collection. By the early 1970’s, West Germany was admitting a thousand times more immigrants per citizen than was the United States.
The concept of the free movement of labor from areas of surplus to areas of deficit was an essential part of the economic unification of Europe that began with the formation of the Common Market, or European Economic Community (EEC), in 1957. Although the underlying treaty provided for free movement of labor among the members, regulations governing that movement were first put in place in 1961, when workers from any member country could accept an officially listed position in another country provided that no native workers were available to take the listed position. In 1964, the native preference was dropped, and the distinction between “permanent” and “seasonal” workers also disappeared. Furthermore, if a position could not be filled by an applicant from anywhere in the EEC, the position could be filled by an applicant from outside the EEC. Workers who remained for four years in one job were eligible for an unrestricted work permit; that is, they could transfer to other employment if they desired. They could also bring their families to join them if housing (generally in short supply in West Germany) was available. By 1968, when the restriction of work applicants to those positions formally listed with the official employment service was dropped, the EEC essentially had established complete freedom of movement for EEC nationals.
The agreements by which Greece and Turkey became associate members of the EEC (signed in 1961 and 1963, respectively) provided for the gradual introduction of freedom of movement within the EEC for Greeks and Turks. The timetable for Greece was suspended when a coup d’état overthrew the democratic government. The timetable for Turkey envisaged the introduction of limited freedom of movement in 1976, with complete freedom of movement in 1985. These arrangements were upset by the termination of foreign hiring in the action taken on November 23, 1973.
Most foreign laborers who came to Germany were officially recruited. Special recruitment agreements were signed with Italy (1955), Greece (1960), Spain (1960), Turkey (1961), Morocco (1963), Portugal (1964), Tunisia (1965), and Yugoslavia (1968). These treaties were implemented through the Federal Employment Office, located in Nuremberg. To facilitate the recruitment process, German officials attached to the Employment Office were stationed in Athens, Greece; Verona, Italy; Madrid, Spain; Istanbul, Turkey; Belgrade, Yugoslavia; Lisbon, Portugal; Casablanca, Morocco; and Tunis, Tunisia. Offices issued work permits to more than two million foreign workers. Work permits initially were valid for one year, but for employees still at the same jobs, they were subject to renewal. The offices in recruiting areas were closed following the termination of foreign recruitment on November 23, 1973.
Although the vast majority of foreign workers in Germany entered following official recruitment, some “illegals” also seeped in. German authorities estimated that they amounted to about 10 percent of all foreign workers in Germany. Many such workers were brought in by middlemen who peddled them to employers who wanted to evade the official recruiting process. Following the termination of official recruitment, the West German government stepped up its efforts to prevent illegal immigration. Tougher laws governing “illegals” were passed in 1975.
Notwithstanding the termination of official recruitment in 1973, the number of foreign workers in Germany declined only moderately after that date. Those foreigners who had already been there for five years were entitled to indefinite extensions of their work permits. Legislation passed in 1978 and 1979 entitled them to extend their residence permits as well.
Significance
The termination of official recruitment of foreign labor on November 23, 1973, marked the end of the great postwar economic boom in Germany. From that point onward, unemployment began to rise in Germany, as well as elsewhere in the EEC. The shortage of labor that had characterized the developed nations of the EEC—not only Germany but also France, the Netherlands, Belgium, and Luxembourg—had turned into a surplus. Experts are divided on the historical causes of this unemployment, although the reintegration of East Germany, with its beleaguered socialist economy, and West Germany in the 1990’s must be seen as a major factor in the more recent increases.
A major cause of unemployment was the two oil shocks, the first in 1973 and the second in 1978. Chancellor Willy Brandt justified the decision announced on November 23, 1973, as a response to the anticipated economic effects of the first oil shock, caused by the announcement by Arab countries that they would curtail oil shipments to certain nations. These two shocks brought about a significant rise in production costs, hampering further expansion of industry. The result was a significant decrease in the number of manufacturing jobs in the years after 1973, and it was particularly these semiskilled factory jobs for which foreigners were recruited. As Germany expanded educational opportunities for its citizens, fewer of them were willing to take monotonous factory jobs; many submitted to unemployment rather than accept such positions.
In addition, during the period of labor shortages many employers substituted capital equipment for labor. This process continued well into the 1970’s and 1980’s, as electronic machine controls and new types of machines made such substitutions possible. Many jobs for which foreign workers had been hired were eliminated, yet those workers who had been in Germany for more than five years were entitled to remain. Foreigners thus added to the numbers of unemployed even though few new foreign workers were admitted. Labor Minister Walter Arendt declared that those foreign workers who already had jobs were not likely to be affected by the government’s decision, but as the number of manufacturing jobs declined, some did become unemployed.
Some economists argue that the substitution of capital for labor was accelerated by government and trade union policy. The socialist government that ruled Germany during the early 1970’s, under the chancellorship of Willy Brandt, was committed to a policy of income redistribution. The government taxed more heavily the incomes of the upper and upper-middle classes, and it encouraged wage settlements in which wages increased more rapidly than the growth of productivity. The result was that the availability of capital declined at the same time that real wages, and real wage costs, rose. Expansion of factories that might have taken place and provided new manufacturing jobs did not occur.
Europe’s less buoyant economy operated against a backdrop of declining world expansion. The two oil shocks transferred vast sums of money from the advanced industrialized countries to the Middle East. This money was therefore not available, or available only in more limited amounts, to fuel additional economic expansion in the industrialized world.
Conservative economists argue that another factor adding to unemployment in Europe was the ever-increasing social costs associated with it. Health benefits, unemployment benefits, substantial vacation benefits, and other social costs, many enshrined in collective bargaining agreements, left less money for production. Moreover, it became increasingly difficult to fire excess employees. This in turn led employers to use overtime rather than take on additional employees when the business cycle turned up, so that recoveries did not cause the job growth that had previously occurred. As a result, most of the job growth after 1973 was in the public sector.
Other factors also played a part. Although by the 1970’s the exodus from agricultural work was largely complete, the postwar baby boom added larger numbers of Germans to the workforce, even though the German birthrate had dropped below the replacement level by the late 1960’s. In addition, many women entered the workforce, taking many white-collar jobs that might otherwise have been occupied by men.
Although the announcement of Germany’s decision to cease recruiting foreign labor was the most striking sign of a fundamental change of direction in the European economy, it was not an isolated event. Most of the other advanced industrial economies of Europe took similar steps at about the same time. In 1976, the Dutch parliament passed a law on foreign laborers that limited the number of foreign employees to twenty per employer. Moreover, employers that wanted to hire a foreigner for a job had to demonstrate that the position could not be filled locally and that it was essential to their operation.
Most highly developed European nations took the position that their population densities were already such that they could not, and should not, in principle become immigration countries. They continued to welcome their own nationals who sought repatriation for any reason, but they took an increasingly negative view of people who wanted to immigrate but who had no prior connection with the land in which they wished to settle. In many European countries, housing was in short supply, and it was argued that this restricted supply should go first to citizens in need. In cases such as that of the Netherlands, which had one of the highest population densities in the world—more than three hundred persons per square kilometer—the rejection of further immigration is easier to understand.
Nevertheless, the end of foreign recruitment posed major problems for the areas from which the bulk of the foreign workers had been recruited. Turkey in particular was heavily affected. It was still in the process of urbanization, and employment opportunities in Turkey’s cities were inadequate to accommodate the large number of Turks pouring out of agricultural areas. Another area heavily affected by the end of recruitment was Yugoslavia, where the inability to export surplus labor may have contributed to the breakup of the country in the 1990’s and the early twenty-first century.
The pressures from the native unemployed also made more difficult the position of foreign workers long resident in the industrialized countries. The growth of xenophobia was expressed in acts of violence against foreign workers in almost all the highly industrialized countries of Europe. As unemployment persisted or increased, the number of acts of violence tended also to increase.
The decision of the German government to terminate the practice of recruiting foreign labor for German factories in 1973 marked a turning point in Europe’s economic progress since World War II. It signaled the end of the rapid economic expansion that had characterized the 1950’s and 1960’s.
Bibliography
Böhning, W. R. The Migration of Workers in the United Kingdom and the European Community. London: Oxford University Press, 1972. Although this study antedates the termination of German recruitment of foreign workers and focuses on the likely impact of British accession to the EEC on international labor migration, it gives substantial information on the effects of the “free migration” policies of the EEC on various member countries.
Drath, Viola Herms. Willy Brandt: Prisoner of His Past. Reprint. Lanham, Md.: Hamilton Books, 2005. An engaging biography of the former chancellor of West Germany.
Entorf, Horst, Wolfgang Franz, Heinz Koenig, and Werner Smolny. “The Development of German Employment and Unemployment: Estimation and Simulation of a Small Macro Model.” In Europe’s Unemployment Problem, edited by Jacques H. Drèze and Charles R. Bean. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1990. Although this study focuses on development of the appropriate algorithm to describe the evolution of the labor market in West Germany, particularly in more recent years, it gives many details that are helpful in understanding the relationship of the immigration ban to the unemployment problem generally.
Franz, Wolfgang, and Heinz Koenig. “The Nature and Causes of Unemployment in the Federal Republic of Germany Since the 1970’s: An Empirical Investigation.” In The Rise in Unemployment, edited by Charles Bean, P. R. G. Layard, and S. J. Nickell. New York: Basil Blackwell, 1986. Account of the German unemployment problem gives numerous statistical details and applies some standard econometric models. Notes that although the concept of labor mobility implied the further migration of migrant laborers or return to their lands of origin when labor demand diminished, this did not occur to any degree in Germany, perhaps because the migrants were aware that they had become accustomed to a higher standard of living than they could hope to achieve at home.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Manpower Policy in Germany. Paris: Author, 1974. Booklet oriented toward public policy measures gives many details concerning how human resources policy operated in Germany in the years prior to the cessation of foreign recruitment. This work’s underlying assumption is that full employment can be achieved and maintained through governmental economic policy.
Reimann, Horst, and Helga Reimann. “Federal Republic of Germany.” In International Labor Migration in Europe, edited by Ronald E. Krane. New York: Praeger, 1979. The Reimanns provide the best short description of the entire process of recruiting foreign labor for German manufacturers. They also discuss some of the social problems that developed in relations between Germans and “guest workers.”