United States v. E. C. Knight Co
United States v. E. C. Knight Co. was a landmark Supreme Court case decided in the late 1890s that addressed the application of the Sherman Antitrust Act against monopolies in the manufacturing sector. The case arose when the American Sugar Company, dominating 98% of the sugar refining industry, faced legal action from President Grover Cleveland's administration due to public concerns about monopolistic practices. In an 8-1 ruling, the Supreme Court determined that the Sherman Antitrust Act did not apply to manufacturing monopolies, asserting that the regulatory power over manufacturing fell under state jurisdiction rather than federal authority. Justice Melville W. Fuller, writing for the majority, emphasized that goods did not qualify as interstate commerce until they were actively transported across state lines.
The dissenting opinion, authored by Justice John Marshall Harlan, argued for a broader interpretation of commerce that included manufacturing processes. Harlan contended that Congress had the constitutional authority to regulate manufacturers and that it had intended to do so with the Sherman Antitrust Act. This case highlighted the ongoing debate over federal versus state regulatory powers and set a precedent that influenced future antitrust litigation, particularly regarding how commerce and manufacturing were defined in legal terms.
United States v. E. C. Knight Co.
Date: January 21, 1895
Citation: 156 U.S. 1
Issue: Sherman Antitrust Act
Significance: In its first decision under the Sherman Antitrust Act (1890), the Supreme Court found that the framers of the act had not intended for it to apply to the manufacturing process.
During the 1890’s, the American Sugar Company was a large monopoly controlling 98 percent of the refining industry. Responding to a public outcry, President Grover Cleveland’s administration filed suit against the monopoly under the Sherman Antitrust Act (1890). By an 8-1 vote, the Supreme Court ruled that the law was not applicable because it had not been designed to prevent a monopoly in manufacturing. In the opinion for the majority, Justice Melville W. Fuller wrote that the power to regulate manufacturing belonged exclusively to the states under their police powers and that the regulatory authority of the federal government was limited to interstate commerce. An article manufactured for sale in another state did not become an article of interstate commerce until it was actually transported as commerce. Fuller did not rule on the constitutionality of the Sherman Act because he assumed that the act had been framed according to the “well-settled principles” of dual federalism.
![The Bosses of the Senate, a cartoon by Joseph Keppler. First published in Puck 1889. Joseph Keppler [Public domain], via Wikimedia Commons 95329624-92010.jpg](https://imageserver.ebscohost.com/img/embimages/ers/sp/embedded/95329624-92010.jpg?ephost1=dGJyMNHX8kSepq84xNvgOLCmsE2epq5Srqa4SK6WxWXS)
In a strong dissent, Justice John Marshall Harlan broadly defined commerce so that it included the buying and selling of goods. He argued that the U.S. Congress could constitutionally regulate some manufacturers and that it had intended to do so in the Sherman Antitrust Act. He insisted, moreover, that only the federal government had the capacity to deal with large business combinations. Although the Court would accept the stream of commerce theory in Swift and Co. v. United States (1905), it did not fully accept Harlan’s view of congressional authority over sugar refineries until Mandeville Island Farms v. American Crystal Sugar Co. (1948).